Spain’s Financing of the Conquest of California, Siglo XVIII

CroppedMora

At Instituto Mora in Mexico D.F., August

Why was it harder for Spain to remove the church from economic power in 18th century California than it was in 18th century Spain?  This was a question I pulled on during my sabbatical year 2013-14.  So often California has been analyzed without looking at Spain or Mexico.  A trip to Mexico in August helped me to right that wrong by meeting Carlos Marichal at the Colegio de Mexico  and Guillermina del Valle Pavon at the Instituto Mora. A paper presented in Lisbon in December permitted me to meet Spanish historians of the economic thought of the 18th century like Luis Perdices.  A presentation at St. Augustine, Florida in March introduced me to Andy Galvan and Kent Lightfoot and put my head back into the US concerns of indigenous culture and survival during the Spanish conquest.  Now, to put these three strands together and answer the question.

In Spain, anger was rising at property in church hands, and my guess is that it was because the church got tax reductions on agricultural produce (and in effect on land) in return for providing social services.  The social services were provided.  The problem was that the church shared its tax privileges with wealthy donors, an alliance which unbalanced the effects of market competition toward big business in agrarian Spain.  I’m guessing again that expelling the Jesuits in 1767 from the Spanish Empire was an extra-legal attempt to remove a large chunk of property from church hands in Spain for transfer to small-holders.  I submitted an article using this interpretation to make sense of the writings of 18th century Spanish economic thinkers Campomanes, Jovellanos and Sempere y Guarinos.

Moving on to Mexico, the Jesuits colonized Baja California starting in 1697.  The government refused to fund the project, but the Jesuits figured they could bring food over the Gulf of California from their missions in Sonora on the other side.  Furthermore, they got private philanthropy.  Every time a 10,000 estate was donated, the Jesuits used the 500 annual income to found a mission.  The missionaries lived frugally, expanded agriculture among Indians–basically, everything they said they would do. The problem for the emerging agrarian market was that the nobility who donated the sheep ranch estates to the Jesuits still harvested the mutton from them for sale to Mexico City’s large market–but now at a 10% discount since the Jesuits were eligible for exemption from the tithe, a 10% tax.  The battle over this tax exemption only ended with the Jesuit expulsion in 1767.  I hope to go back to Mexico City in February 2015 to present this idea to the Asociedad Mexicana de Historia Economica, and we’ll see if it passes muster.

Enter Alta Californiain 1769. King Carlo Borbone didn’t trust an alliance between church and private sector, so he funded the conquest of California directly, and gave 80% of the funds to soldiers who reported to him directly, and only 20% to missions.  The soldiers were hoping there would be no missions at all, so they could take Indian land directly and use Indian people as laborers directly, but my guess is that missions were just too cost effective at keeping Indians quiet for Carlo Borbone to give up that age old-ally, the church.  He replaced independent Jesuits with Franciscans he thought would be pliable.  He did not count on Serra, who turned out to be very good at winning bureaucratic battles in Mexico City, so that the non profit Franciscans retained control of land rather than for-profit settlers.   I’m going to sort out the mission Indian vs. settler property rights by looking at Los Angeles 1769 to 1860 in my course American Property Rights in Spring 2015.

Franciscan-Indian relations are an emotional topic for us Californians (I grew up near San Francisco in what was once the territory of the Huchiun, and was later Rancho San Antonio).  I want to make sure I understand the institutional set-up correctly before I give my answer.  So right now I’m estimating contraband trade in the Pacific–not just trade with the British after 1800, but also trade with Spanish American ships from 1769 to 1800.  It’s probably no accident that Spain’s Philippine business got reorganized in 1769 on one side of the Pacific, and California was taken over on the other.  And maybe there is a link between Pacific Rim commerce and the well-being of California peoples such as the Kumeyaay, Chumash, Esselen, and Ohlone. David Igler argued in 2013 that British ships may have brought disease, and I’m reading about all these sick sailors put ashore by Spanish ships at San Quentin, Los Cabos, Todos Santos in Baja and Monterey and San Diego much earlier than that.  If I saw a way that these commercial ties influenced mortality rates, then I might see how this economist could weigh in on the debates so central to Californians.

Portugal 026

With Luis Perdices and Estrella Trincado, Lisboa Diciembre

Books by the following were deeply appreciated this year: Campomanes, Jovellanos, Sempere y Guarinos, Richard Herr, Vicent Llombart, Regina Grafe, Luis Perdices, Harry Crosby, H.E. Priestley, Carlos Marichal, Guillermina del Valle, Deni Trejo, Mariano Bonialian, Carmen Yuste. Without moral support, no project gets anywhere, so thank you John Johnson, Gavin Wright, Bill Taylor, Luis Perdices, Richard Salvucci, Bob Senkewicz, and Richard Herr.   Thank you Linda Madden for working that ILL in overdrive!  Thank you to Keene State and Mary Kay Duggan for financing travel.  Now may my children have patience as I revise and resubmit and keep on writing.

Posted in Uncategorized | Comments Off

Bretton Woods 1944: Freeing Trade to do Good

My first night in New Hampshire was spent dining with graduate school friends at the Mt. Washington Hotel in Bretton Woods, New Hampshire.  The lobby told us that financial ministers from 44 countries met in there, with Keynes from Britain and Harry Dexter White of the United States Treasury leading the theoretical discussions–but what was at stake?  What were the implications of these legalistic clauses?  Between 2007 and 2011, my students and I discussed these questions in ISECON 360: History of Economic Thought, and I published the answers in RRPE, December 2013 (see link to right). Keynes’ Bretton Woods proposal was his attempt to prevent free trade from deindustrializing Britain.  The article is my attempt to figure out how Keynes would advise the US today to defang free trade so that it would benefit working people.

Posted in Uncategorized | Comments Off

Deindustrialization/Reindustrialization, Keene 1970-2012

 

Students Greg Hall, Pat Murphy and Dan Bayrouty with Prof. Marie Duggan

The juniors and seniors of Econ 455: US Economic History were recently invited to discuss our research on Keene’s industrial history with leaders in the business community.

 

 

 

 

Mary Ann Kristiansen of the Hannah Grimes Center for Entrepreneurship faciliated the meeting of business leaders and students.

Ray Anderson (Knappe and Koester) and Don Brehm (founder of Pneumo)

 

Ray Anderson of Knappe and Koester had given our class a tour of his cutting-edge machine shop earlier in the semester.  He feels the pressure of international competition sharply, and maneuvers carefully to innovate and expand while cutting costs.

 

Don Brehm founded Pneumo in 1962 with his invention, the air bearing guage.  Mr. Brehm told us that passion makes the difference, and government contracts played a key role in the growth of his business. 

 

 

David Schuster

David Schuster explored the industrial cluster spauned by Pneumo with metrology, diamond turning machines, and optics in Keene. 

 

 

Michelle Partridge

 

Michelle Patridge described how an industrial cluster promotes innovation.

 

 

 

Greg Hall discussed the industrial history of the Connecticut River Valley, including Pratt and Whitney in Hartford, and Bryant Grinding in Springfield, VT.

 

 

Francis Bonnell (sitting with Norm Fiske of RCAM) discussed the printing business at Markem under F.A. and David Putnam.

 

 

 

We were enthused to learn that Ken Abbott’s ABTech is a family business, with three generations participating.  ABTech makes air bearing guages today.

Maureen Curtis of Timken MPB reminded us that a good financial expert can shine the light on the origina of  profits or losses.  She also echoed a sentiment we had heard from our interviews: not enough young people are attracted by manufacturing careers.  Student Chris Hinchey discussed how MPB came to Keene and founded precision grinding here, and Joe Katin discussed how Timken had invested against the cycle in a smelting plant in the early 1980s, using the latest technology from Japan.

 

Dan Bayrouty discussed that machinists like to be maanged by hands-on people, which is one reason workers on Springfield, VT were unhappy when Textron bought out Fellows Gearshaper, Bryant Grinding, and Jones and Lamson in the 1970s.  Pat Murphy explained that sales of machine tool firms are extremely cyclical, and in downturns the conglomerate may favor businesses that are less impacted.  Joe Bohenek discussed the culture of innovation promoted by social ties between technical people; for example, the Keene Astronomy Club may foster ties between people who make lenses. 

Joe Bohenek

Mayor Kendall Lane and Jim Pelto of SPDI listen to Norm Fiske of RCAM

 Jim Pelto teaches the next generation of young people who will go into manufacturing at Keene State’s Sustainability and Product Design major (SPDI).  Norm Fiske brings the educational community together with business needs through the Regional Center for Advanced Manufacturing (RCAM).

Posted in Uncategorized | 1 Comment